You may have come across a
social experiment called The Ultimatum Game. In this game player A (Jack) is given
some money, say £50, and asked how much, if any, he proposes to offer to player
B (Jill). Jill can accept or reject Jack's offer - but if she rejects it,
neither of them gets anything. If Jack and Jill were rational
income-maximisers, Jack would offer just £1 and Jill would accept it, because 1
free pound is better than nothing. But this very rarely happens, because humans
are not rational income-maximisers.
Having a voracious appetite
for fairness, the Jills of this world often reject free money from the Jacks of
this world if the offers are not perceived to be an equitable distribution of
the £50. Such sensibilities play out more broadly in society, which is why
there is a correlation between trade and fairness. This was demonstrated in an
interesting study from Herb Gintis that I read about in Matt Ridley's book The Rational Optimist:
"People in fifteen mostly small-scale tribal
societies were enticed to play the Ultimatum Game. Those societies with the
least experience of dealing with outsiders were the most hard-hearted,
ungenerous and narrowly ‘rational’. Machiguenga slash-and-burn farmers from the
Amazon most often offered just 15 per cent of the sum to their co-subjects, and
in all but one cases, the second player accepted. Likewise, a Hadza hunter-gatherer
from Tanzania
usually makes a very small offer and experiences few rejections.
On the other hand, players from those societies that
are most integrated into modern markets, such as the Orma nomads of Kenya or
the Achuar subsistence gardeners of Ecuador, will usually offer half the money
just as a Western undergraduate would. The whale-hunting Lamalera of the island
of Lembata in Indonesia, who need to coordinate large teams of strangers on
hunts, offer on average 58 per cent – as if investing the windfall in acquiring
new obligations. Much the same happens in two New Guinea tribes, the Au and Gnau,
whose members often make ‘hyper-fair’ offers and yet see them rejected: in such
cultures, gifts can be a burden to the receiver because they carry an
obligation to reciprocate.”
“The lesson of this study is that, on the whole,
having to deal with strangers teaches you to be polite to them, and that in
order for such generosity to emerge, costly punishment of selfishness may be
necessary. Rejecting the offer is costly for the second player, but he reckons
it is worth it to teach the first player a lesson. The argument is not that
exchange teaches people to be kind; it is that exchange teaches people to
recognise their enlightened self-interest lies in seeking cooperation. Here,
then, lies a clue to the unique human attribute of being able to deal with
strangers, to extend the division of labour to include even your enemies.”
As well as the
progression-explosion of individual well-being and higher standard of living
that capitalism has bestowed upon us, it's also essential to note how good
capitalism has been and continues to be for the collective benefits of human
society, not just in more than material gains, but in corporate kindness too. A
society that relies on trade relies on cooperation, respect, fairness, justice
and mutual toleration - the whole edifice depends on it. The free exchange of
goods, services and ideas does not just make us materially better off, it makes
us nicer, more respectful, more tolerant people to be around too - and those
collective benefits play out in our living in all-round better societies.
And the kinds of society
we have created through increased trade are uniquely human too. In the animal
kingdom there are all kinds of cooperation and collaboration within a species -
between other primates, between ants, between lions, between wolves, between
elephants, between bees, between birds - you name it. But as a rule,
cooperation and collaboration between unrelated strangers seems to not occur
very often in the rest of the animal kingdom - there are almost no cases of
unconnected animals involved in mutually beneficial transactions in the humans
are when we trade. There is even a ratchet-type pattern of trade occurring with
the development of farming in various countries independently at different
times in history when the right conditions were met - Peru first, then China ,
then Mexico , then North
America and Africa, and then Europe .
Perhaps my favourite
example of the joy of trade is when I buy an Indian takeaway. People with whom
I have little in common cook incredibly tasty food that I value much more than
the money I pay to consume it. At the same time, I help the people that sell to me
to make a living, and both agents are made better off. In feeding me, the
proprietors get to feed their family too. And this extends right across the
marketplace.
We are all making each other better off by trade. We are contributing to a nicer, safer, more respectful, more tolerant society, in which our own personal pursuits are helping enrich total strangers too - and when aggregated, it is sufficient to make everyone in that society richer and more prosperous.
Commerce has done more to
combat racism, sexism, and unfair discrimination of any kind, and the
alleviation of poverty for billions, than any government program. How bizarre
then that we live in an age in which trade has done more than anything else to
tackle poverty, hardship, injustice, corruption, prejudice, bigotry and
disunity, yet the generation that has been the biggest beneficiaries are the
most vociferous opponents of it in history.
No comments:
Post a Comment