Education secretary Nicky Morgan wants to give parents greater
choice in state-funded schools because she thinks schools will “up their game”. We hear this a lot
from politicians - they regularly tell us they are trying to do us a favour by
giving us more free choice in our public services. Basically, they are trying
to sell us the choice-driven qualities of a private enterprise consumer market.
Alas, what they fail to realise, or don't want to tell you, is that choice is always going to be sub-optimal when the
things being chosen are funded by taxpayers.
Suppose the government nationalised handbags and gave them away for
free by obtaining money from our taxes. What would happen? Demand would
increase, but supply wouldn't be able to keep up with the demand, because there
are a limited number of handbags. Consider a Gucci handbag for £2000 and a Next
handbag for £30. Taxpayers cannot fund Gucci handbags for everyone, so they
must be rationed. So wealthier people will have the Gucci handbags (because
they've paid more tax) and others will queue for Next products.
The problem arises because the government won't be able to match
supply to demand. The reason being: it doesn't know how much everyone values
handbags, so nationalising handbags would be unsuccessful. The free market of
private enterprise doesn't have this problem because the market of supply and
demand dictates prices of handbags and tailors those prices to how much people
value them.
Rich Rachel may wish to buy a Gucci handbag for £2000 and Skint
Sally may only be able to afford a Next handbag for £30. But that doesn't just
tell us about wealth; it tells us about desire for handbags too. Loaded Lorraine may have more
money than Rich Rachel, but she might have no care for ostentatious handbags
and instead prefer to spend £30 on a Next handbag and use the remaining £1970
to pay for a holiday or a painting. The right supply of handbags (and holidays
and paintings) depends on how consumers make the trade offs.
Public services paid for by the taxpayers are not better off with
the introduction of more choice because the government does not have the supply
and demand price mechanism to factor in consumer choices - and thus it has no
metric by which it can check people's valuation of the different products.
Understanding this is the key to understanding why increased choice in
taxpayer-funded services fails to capture what people value.
Suppose we have a city in which there are two
only schools - let's call them S1 and S2. One of the schools is bound to be better
than the other - let's say S1 is better. In a public sector system where prices
are not attached to value, everyone is going to be paying for S1 or S2, but
some parents are going to receive better service than others (apply this to
state run anything and the same applies). In a state funded, unpriced system
(obtained from taxation) everyone is going to prefer S1 over S2, and half the
city's population is going to be disappointed that they got S2.
Let's take it to an extreme and suppose that
there was no more nationalised education - and that schools were fee-charging,
with tax for education (roughly about £10,000 per year, per person) staying in
the pockets of families. Now S1 and S2 would operate under a much more
efficient system. Here's what would happen. By charging for services, the
inequality between S1 and S2 would turn into something better; there'd be an
increase in demand for education in S1, which would bid up prices, which would
engender lower prices at S2. This process would carry on until the
differentiation between S1 and S2 matched the value parents placed on them. Those
in S2 would be compensated by paying less for a less-good service, and because
parents would be considering the average trade-off, they'd be free to splash
out on better education, or have cheaper education and more money in their
pockets.
My thought model only had 2 choices - imagine
how much better with dozens of choices. Good and expensive or not so good and
cheap is the kind of choice we should value (‘not so good’ ought not to mean
‘bad’ though). We are constantly being told that it's wrong to disadvantage
those who can't pay for better education like the wealthy can. But not only is
it undesirable to attempt to suppress those opportunities, it is also the case
that if we stopped wealthy people's ability to buy more than their poor
counterparts then monetary value would go out the window. Of course politicians
don't really mean this - and neither do the electorate - they really mean
everyone is entitled to a decent education. But this favours supply and demand
in a free market because it is when choice is obtained and prices match value
that standards improve.
I'll wager quite a few of you are
uncomfortable talking about schools in this way - after all, education is such
an important thing that all talk of cheaper, less good education is surely to
be guilty of failing our children. Yes it would be if that were the case -
however, given that education is such a precious resource it is precisely for
that reason that competition ought to be the mechanism to improve standards.
Of course, it’s worth noting that no one has
any trouble understanding this if the subject is mobile phones, cars or
televisions. Everyone agrees that if mobile phones, cars and televisions had been funded from
taxation for the past 25 years that the products would be far less good, and more
expensive (or poorly allocated). Tax-funded projects would generate far less
concern for providing consumers with better products at better prices. Why,
then, do so few people understand this same principle when it comes to schools?
A system in which schools are funded by taxation frees schools from
such a high burden of satisfying consumers' preferences, just as would be the
case if this applied to Sony, Panasonic or Apple. By and large private schools
provide better educations than state-funded schools, not just because fee
paying schools contain a greater proportion of bright pupils, but also because,
just like Sony, Panasonic and Apple, the school has market pressure to deliver
the standard of education that the parents demand at the price paid.
The popular assertion from politicians that tax-funded schools are
best because children deserve a good education gets things backwards. It is
because education is such a vital resource that it needs price signals and
market competition to allocate those resources better.
Finally, I will grant you that at the moment we are not quite
ready to overhaul the current system and make children's education solely a
matter for market forces - which means such a system ought to be brought in
gradually, and tweaked and refined over time, not piled on to parents in one foul swoop.
But even so, to suggest that in the meantime more taxpayer-funded
consumer choice will continue to generate a healthier competition that can greatly
increase the standards of education in this country is at best naively
optimistic, and at worst, just plain wrong.
Finally,
if you are having trouble imaging a life where schools aren't the
responsibility of the state, you may like to know (if you don't already) that
politicians only took over education in Britain as late as the late 19th
century, and in that period a much higher proportion of working class people
could read and write competently (90%), whereas nowadays it is thought to be
somewhere between 75-80%.
No comments:
Post a Comment