I don’t know how much longer we are going to have to keep hearing from politicians that they plan to appease the electorate (they never use those words, of course) by artificially creating industrial jobs in Britain (particularly in the north of England). When they tell you this, you know they are either lying, or they don’t understand how industry works. Industries and services are effective for one reason – the economy has a price system that almost perfectly balances the interests of the buyer and seller. Consequently, it cannot be interfered with artificially with any predictable success because the competitive marketplace aligns private and public interests (and prices) far more effectively than any Government can by means of artifice (some forms of regulation excepted, but they are not important here).
I do
admit, though, this self-governing system is quite rare; in most areas of life
the needs of the individual and the greater good are not ideally matched. In a football stadium when an exciting
incident occurs everyone stands up for a better view, which means nobody
succeeds in improving the greater good.
At busy house parties, every individual talks louder than they need to,
due to everyone else talking louder than they need to – so all guests strain
their voice boxes more than they would need to if attendees were mindful of the
greater good. In a fuel crisis the
majority over consume, leaving many with no means of consumption. The economy is the rare exception to the
rule; if you invent a brand new product, and have no idea how much to sell it
for, the system of supply and demand will soon put your product at a rate that
matches the value the consumers place on it.
So despite what you are frequently told, MPs cannot easily interfere
with the supply and demand balance of the market economy. That’s the first mistake made, or lie told,
by too many politicians.
The
second is even greater – they make mistakes, or tell lies, about our own
industry. As much as it rankles people
in Britain (particularly those outside of London), there is one simple reason
why British manufacturing has gone downhill; manufactured goods acquired from
other countries makes Britain richer (by the way, it also makes the exporting
countries richer too). How do I know
that things would be worse if anyone tried to change Britain ’s manufacturing exports
artificially? I know because in the vast
majority of cases the price system in the competitive marketplace couldn’t have
favoured the companies that are no longer manufacturing in Britain – quite
simply because consumers started to buy from cheaper manufacturers abroad.
This is
the essence of a global trade system that ideally aligns supply and
demand. Amazingly there are people who
deny this is true. I can offer a
schoolboy example that shows the logic is correct. Pretend that instead of two countries we have
two schools – School A and School B, neither of which is permitted to trade
with the other. Johnny at School A has a
monopoly on pencil cases. Johnny can
sell Billy a pencil case for £5. Now
because of a new policy which enables School A to trade with School B, Billy
can now buy a pencil case from Charlie in School B for £3. Johnny has two choices, he can match
Charlie’s £3 selling price or he can find something else to trade in. If he chooses the latter he will ensure he is
no worse off than a £2 loss, otherwise he might as well choose to match
Charlie’s £3. So the worst case scenario
is that Johnny carries on trading, losing £2 per unit. Billy’s £2 gain matches
Johnny’s £2 loss, so there is no net gain or loss. But now consider Freddy at School A. Freddy, who was never willing to pay £5 for a
pencil case, buys one for £3 from Charlie in School B, and goes home happy (as
does Charlie with another sale).
Billy’s
gain and Johnny’s loss cancel each other out, but Charlie’s gain amounts to a
net gain. The logic is compelling and
simple – in net terms both School A and School B benefit from being able to
trade with each other. Instead of two
schools, relate that model to every country in the world, multiply that simple
pencil case model by factors of billions to allow for an open and competitive
market, and different countries’ resources, strengths and geographical
positions, and it is obvious that each country benefits from unconstrained
trade potential.
But
that’s not the whole story; I have only said why free international trade is
good for economies. There is another
important factor in this picture – impeding the process of free international
trade actually harms the people the Government wants to protect – its own
industry (and thus, its own citizens).
Here’s how it happens. Let’s use
a simple and extreme illustration to explain what is a more complex but no less
valid truth about why Government interference is bad. Let’s suppose there is a car factory in
Newcastle that isn’t doing as well as the Executives or the Government would
like, due to consumers’ preference for cars in Japan. The Government introduces a policy that
favours car production in Newcastle over car imports from Japan. How on Earth could that not be good for the
British economy – Britain’s gain is Japan’s loss, right? Wrong.
Quite simply, what you put into the pockets of the car factory in
Newcastle you take out of someone else’s pockets elsewhere in Britain (as well
as having people probably paying more for their cars). Consider Slough’s boiler factory; what you
don’t see is an almost invisible chain of events; the boilers made in Slough
are shipped off to Japan and sold to a company that makes its money producing
nuclear reactors, the buyers of which are companies who trade in mineral oils,
and those companies deal with companies who make cars in Japan and ship them to
Britain.
In other
words, there is a complex economic process that is going on outside of your
peripheral vision, whereby both the car factory in Newcastle and the boiler
factory in Slough are both bringing cars into Britain. That is to say, if you protect the car
factory in Newcastle from competition you must damage Slough’s boiler factory
because somewhere down the line they are the competition. So the next time you hear a politician
announcing how much he or she wants to do to protect British producers in one
industry from foreign competition, be aware that he or she is unknowingly
proposing an action that hurts other industries in Britain, and amounts to a
net loss in economic efficiency.
No comments:
Post a Comment